In lieu of an abstract, here is a brief excerpt of the content:

Reviewed by:
  • How the Weak Win Wars: A Theory of Asymmetric Conflict
  • Jeremy Black
How the Weak Win Wars: A Theory of Asymmetric Conflict. By Ivan Arreguín-Toft. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006. ISBN 0-521-54869-1. Tables. Figures. Appendixes. Notes. References. Index. Pp. xv, 250. $29.99.

A political scientist with a background of service in the U.S. Army, including as a military intelligence analyst, Dr. Arreguín-Toft sets out to offer a theoretical perspective on why the weak win wars. He does so by means of a theoretical section which is then followed by five case studies: Russia in the Caucasus, 1830–59, the Second Boer War, the Italo-Ethiopian War of 1935–40, the U.S.A. in Vietnam, and the Soviet Union in Afghanistan. A number of variables that might explain the contrasting success of strong states in asymmetric conflicts are evaluated, for example "democratic social squeamishness". Arreguín-Toft concludes that the strategic interaction thesis best explains the situation: "According to this thesis, the interaction of the strategies actors use during a conflict predicts the outcome of that conflict better than competing explanations. If . . . when [End Page 297] actors employ similar strategic approaches . . . relative power explains the outcome . . . when actors employ opposite strategic approaches . . . weak actors are much more likely to win" (p. 18).

The case studies are each examined from the perspective of the overall thesis. For example, as far as Afghanistan is concerned, the author argues that strategic interaction explains why the Soviets failed in 1980–82—by pursuing a conventional attack strategy against a mujahideen guerrilla warfare strategy. In 1983, however, the Soviets switched to a barbarism strategy, but, Arreguín-Toft argues, still failed because the mujahideen were able to rely on intelligence and logistical support from foreign powers.

Much of the discussion will not surprise military historians, and some may be dismayed by the heavy emphasis on the theoretical model, rather than detailed research on operational and strategic issues, not least the decisionmaking processes of the combatants. Some readers may also dissent from the conclusions as applied to current American security concerns and foreign policy:

If it wants to win the peace . . . it must support its resort to arms by eliminating foreign policy double standards and by increasing its capacity and willingness to use methods other than violence to resolve or deter conflicts around the world. So long as the United States continues to support corrupt and repressive regimes in Latin America, Africa, the Middle East, and Asia, terrorists and insurgents will continue to frustrate US interests in global peace and prosperity.

(p. 227)

This appears a simplistic account of the politics of much of the world, of American policy and of the response to it, each of which is over-determined to accord with a model. More generally, it is valuable to think in theoretical terms and Arreguín-Toft raises an important point when he demonstrates that strong states have become less effective with time. However, rather than differentiating between causal factors, it is more pertinent to argue in favour of multifactor explanations that cannot be readily separated. Much scholarship fails to address theoretical factors explicitly but, nevertheless, implicitly rests on a theoretical base. It may well be better to discuss the theories explicitly, but to do so it is best not to adopt an overly rigid approach.

Jeremy Black
University of Exeter Exeter
, England, United Kingdom
...

pdf

Share